Monopoly Capital at the Half-Century Mark
[Monopoly Capital]
represents the first serious attempt to extend Marx’s model of
competitive capitalism to the new conditions of monopoly capitalism.
Howard J. Sherman, American Economic Review, 19661
A
list of Marxist writers on political economy [since the Second World
War] whose works are known to a relatively large number of activists
would be very short, at least until the beginning of the 1960s. Three
names would stand out: Sweezy, Dobb, and Baran. It is not by chance that
the label of “neo-Marxist’ has been applied to their works, so that
they appear to be the only inheritors of the tradition of Marxist
political economy. Within the German student movement, for example,
Baran and Sweezy seem to be the two theoreticians whose works have been
best received and most widely read.
Mario Cogoy, Les Temps Modernes, 19722
A half-century after its publication, Paul Baran and Paul Sweezy’s Monopoly Capital remains the single most influential work in Marxian political economy to emerge in the United States.3 Like any great theoretical work that has retained its influence over a long period of time, Monopoly Capital‘s
significance today derives not simply from the book itself, but from
the complex debates that it has generated. In recent years, interest in
Baran and Sweezy’s magnum opus has
revived, primarily for two reasons: (1) the global resurgence of
debates over the constellation of issues that their work
addressed—including economic stagnation, monopoly, inequality,
militarism and imperialism, multinational corporations, economic waste,
surplus capital absorption, financial speculation, and plutocracy; and
(2) the new, fundamental insights into the book’s origins resulting from
the publication of its two missing chapters and the public release of
Baran and Sweezy’s correspondence.
I shall divide this introduction on the influence and development of the argument of Monopoly Capital over
the last fifty years into three parts: (1) a brief treatment of the
book itself and its historical context; (2) a discussion of responses
to Monopoly Capital,
and of the development of the tradition that it represented, during its
first four decades, up to the Great Financial Crisis that began in
2007; and (3) an assessment of the continuing significance of monopoly
capital theory in the context of the historical period stretching from
the Great Financial Crisis to the present.
The Work
Monopoly Capital was subtitled An Essay on the American Economic and Social Order,
referring both to the book’s provisional character and historical
limitations on its scope. Baran and Sweezy made it clear that their
intention was not to try to replace Marx’s Capital itself,
but rather to raise the question of modifications in the system’s laws
of motion under monopoly capitalism. For example, Monopoly Capital did
not include an analysis of the labor process—instead, it simply assumed
the continuing validity of Marx’s own theory of labor exploitation.
Their book took its primary significance from the changing character of
the individual unit of capital, or the typical capitalist firm, over the
course of the twentieth century. As a result of such changes, they
argued, monopoly must now be “put…at the very center of the analytical
effort” in any attempt to understand the latest stage of capitalist
development. In this way they sought to give a sharper meaning to what
thinkers like Rudolf Hilferding and V. I. Lenin had referred to as
“finance capitalism” and “the monopoly stage of capitalism.”4
The
dominance of monopolistic accumulation at the center of the system
meant that the whole nature of competition under capitalism had been
altered, taking on the form of oligopolistic rivalry. Individual firms
or small clusters of firms, protected by barriers to entry and by the
sheer scale of their operations, gained extensive control over price,
output, investment, and innovation. Such giant firms increasingly
operated on a global scale as multinational corporations, and attained
significant leverage over the state. These new, mammoth entities were
long-lived accumulation mechanisms, constantly mutating into larger,
more centralized corporations. The typical firm was not a price taker
but a price maker. Genuine price competition or price wars of the kind
that would destabilize the co-respective relations between oligopolistic
enterprises was effectively banned. Above all, such firms enjoyed
widening profit margins and typically grew in size relative to the
economy as a whole. It was these features of the firm under monopoly
capitalism that led Baran and Sweezy to introduce their thesis of “the
tendency of surplus to rise”—monopoly capitalism’s inversion of Marx’s
famous theory of the tendency of the rate of profit to fall.5
The
economic surplus was conceived in its simplest definition as the
difference between the costs of production and the price of the actual
(or potential) output generated.6 Under
the monopoly stage of capitalism, the primary contradiction at the
center of the system shifted from the generation of surplus to its
absorption. Capital continually produced more surplus than it could
absorb in existing and prospective markets. The result was a tendency to
economic stagnation, since surplus (ex ante) that was not absorbed meant economic losses to the system, pulling down growth.
Under
monopoly capital, therefore, the economy confronted chronic problems of
surplus absorption, excess capacity, unemployment, and underemployment.
“The normal state of the monopoly capitalist economy,” Baran and Sweezy contended, “is stagnation.”7 Even
technological innovation could not suffice to overcome this tendency,
since apart from what they called “epoch-making innovations” on the
level of the steam engine, the railroad, or the automobile—which changed
the whole spatial and temporal context of production while also
expanding demand—innovations tended to be endogenously controlled by
monopoly capital itself, and introduced only in accordance with the
investment needs of dominant corporations. (None of this meant that
Baran and Sweezy underestimated technological change itself. In 1957
Sweezy was the anonymous author of one of the most prescient analyses of
technological development of the age, in the form of a pamphlet
entitled The Scientific-Industrial Revolution, written for the Wall Street corporate research group Model, Roland and Stone.)8
Yet
the monopoly capitalist economy did not simply sink into a deep
depression. Instead, the system developed its own internal and external
defenses, promoting economic expansion through economic waste and state
spending—the latter often in the form of unproductive expenditures, such
as military spending. The result was a growing irrationality at every
level of the economy—from the sales effort to product obsolescence to
socially inefficient and meaningless products to the expenses of empire.
Such waste resulted in the squandering of human lives and effort, and
the transformation of capitalism’s “creative destruction,” as Joseph
Schumpeter famously called it, into a more pervasive, uncreative
destruction—toward the products of human labor, the environment, and
ultimately humanity itself.
Assessing
the scale of waste in the economy, Baran and Sweezy returned to the old
concept of unproductive labor, extending it to account not only for
what was unproductive from the standpoint of the individual capitalist (i.e., not producing surplus value), but also from the standpoint of capitalism in general (in which the waste of monopolistic competition, e.g. advertising, became visible), as well as from the standpoint of society as a whole (i.e., from the critical view of a more rationally planned, socialist society).9
The impact of Baran and Sweezy’s Monopoly Capital on
readers in the late 1960s and early 1970s had much to do with the way
it engaged with, but also transcended, the Keynesian Revolution,
associated with John Maynard Keynes’s 1936 General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money—a
work which had given new life to orthodox economics, enhancing the role
of the state in the management of the economy. At the heart of Keynes’s
incomplete break with neoclassical economics (which later allowed his
analysis to be reincorporated into neoclassical theory in what Joan
Robinson aptly called “bastard Keynesianism”) was his critique, along
lines first developed by Marx, of Say’s Law of markets, whereby supply
was thought to create its own demand.10 Say’s
Law had suggested that economic crises could only stem from supply-side
pressures—that is, from increased costs, particularly of labor—and
never from the demand side, i.e., from a lack of effective demand.
Keynes decisively demonstrated the logical fallacy of Say’s Law, and
envisioned a new role for governments in the promotion of effective
demand through state spending.11
However,
the major breakthroughs in the Keynesian Revolution were first
developed not by Keynes but by the Polish Marxist economist Michał
Kalecki, several years prior to the publication of the General Theory.
(Ironically, Kalecki was often seen as a mere follower of Keynes and a
developer of his ideas.) In a series of works from the early 1930s
through the 1960s, Kalecki developed an analysis of demand-side
weaknesses in the capitalist economy, based in the concepts of class and
monopoly. He put particular stress on the rise in “the degree of
monopoly.”12 Kalecki’s
close colleague at the Oxford Institute of Statistics during the Second
World War, the Austrian economist Josef Steindl, was to extend this
analysis in his 1952 Maturity and Stagnation in American Capitalism, connecting the growth of monopolistic accumulation to the tendency toward economic stagnation.13
It was on the basis of Kalecki and Steindl’s work in particular—as well as their own earlier analyses, in Sweezy’sThe Theory of Capitalist Development (1942) and Baran’s The Political Economy of Growth (1957)—that
Baran and Sweezy developed the distinctive critique of the post-Second
World War U.S. capitalist system that distinguished Monopoly Capital.14 Going
beyond Kalecki and Steindl, they advanced an analysis that was as
political as it was economic. The book’s focus on militarism and
imperialist interventions transformed them from mere accidental
historical developments—as in liberal thought and even in many radical
readings—into structurally necessary elements of capitalism’s global
expansion. The real causes of the Vietnam War were laid bare. The
tactics of Madison Avenue, and the rise of the so-called consumer
society were linked with a powerful critique of the sales effort under
monopoly capitalism. Institutional racism and its connection to
imperialism were exposed. In this sense, Baran and Sweezy offered a
fairly complete “essay-sketch” of the dominant issues of the age, in
line with the epigraph to their book, Hegel’s famous statement that “the
truth is the whole.”15
The
most obvious problem facing Marxian theory in the 1960s was the failure
of the working class in the industrial capitalist economies to continue
their struggle against capitalism, a failure that had become even more
apparent after the system rose out of the Great Crisis represented by
the First World War, the Great Depression, and the Second World War.
Although revolutions had broken out in the periphery and semi-periphery
of the system in Russia and the third world, the working classes in the
advanced capitalist centers had become increasingly reformist and even
conservative. Baran and Sweezy’s analysis, while continuing to
sympathize with working-class struggles in the United States,
particularly among its most marginalized populations, gave more
attention to revolutionary potential of third world peoples struggling
against imperialism. Nevertheless, the tendency toward stagnation
suggested that continuing economic contradictions at the center of the
system could conceivably lead at some point to a more rebellious working
class there as well.
In its clarity of thought and style—a quality that even the Economist commended—Monopo ly Capital was
able to present many of the complex contradictions associated with the
rise of the giant corporation in easily accessible terms.16 Still,
most readers were mainly influenced by Baran and Sweezy’s more obvious
historical observations, and failed to recognize the depth of the theory
behind these observations, or their larger implications. Subsequent
radical thought was slow to recognize the book’s subtler insights and to
incorporate its ideas creatively and constructively. In each successive
decade, Monopoly Capital was
read differently, reflecting nothing so much as the changing historical
conditions of the times. The range of responses to theirmagnum opus by
generations of radicals reveals much about the developing
political-economic critique of capitalism since the Second World War.
The Debate on Monopoly Capital: The First Four Decades
1966–1975
Paul
Sweezy had early on established a strong reputation as an assistant
professor of economics at Harvard, publishing pioneering work in the
theory of oligopolistic pricing and other areas. In 1942 Sweezy had
writtenThe Theory of Capitalist Development,
widely considered the finest synthesis of Marxian economics of its
time. On being released from military service at the end of the Second
World War, he resigned his position at Harvard with more than two years
still remaining on his contract, forsaking the possibility of tenure in
order to concentrate on his writing and his hope of eventually starting a
socialist magazine. (Four years later, in May 1949, the first issue of Monthly Review appeared, edited by Sweezy and Leo Huberman.)17
From
1949 until his death in 1964, Paul Baran was a professor of economics
at Stanford University—and the only Marxist economist to hold a tenured
position at a major U.S. university. In 1957, he published The Political Economy of Growth,
helping to launch dependency theory as a radical response to mainstream
development economics in the post-Second World War period.
Considering
their respective reputations, Baran and Sweezy’s joint work was eagerly
awaited by critics of the system all over the world. It did not appear
suddenly: the book had a gestation time of about ten years, and only
came out in 1966, two years after Baran’s death. Sweezy prepared the
final manuscript based on chapters that they had authored individually
and then reworked together, reluctantly leaving out two additional
chapters drafted by Baran that had not been sufficiently revised by the
two of them. (These two chapters, “Some Theoretical Implications” and “The Quality of Monopoly Capitalist Society: Culture and Communications,” were published in Monthly Review in July-August 2012 and July-August 2013, respectively.)18In 1965, Sweezy explored the possibility of publishing Monopoly Capital with
the mainstream British publisher McGibbon and Kee. Although the book
received a highly favorable external reviewer’s report which was passed
on to Sweezy, for reasons still unclear, no contract was signed, and the
book was published by Monthly Review Press on March 26, 1966, the
second anniversary of Baran’s death.19
The initial response to Monopoly Capital was
startling, especially for a work of Marxian economics during a tense
phase of the Cold War. It was reviewed in many of the leading journals
of the economic profession, both in the United States and abroad,
including the American Economic Review, Journal of Political Economy,Econometrica, Economic Journal, and elsewhere. Beyond the academy, it attracted notice in the New York Review of Books, the New York Herald Tribune, the Economist, the Nation, New Left Review, Science and Society (which
published a full symposium on the work), and other outlets. Its sales
were large for a book of its kind, and extraordinary for a work in
Marxian economics at the time, reaching 50,000 copies in its
English-language edition in just the first five years, and in the same
period it was translated into eight additional languages.20
Monopoly Capital had
an extraordinary effect on the New Left emerging in the United States
in the late 1960s and early 1970s, and the book in many ways provided
the primary basis on which radical political economy developed in the
period—particularly in economics and sociology. This was most apparent
with the founding of the Union for Radical Political Economics (URPE) in
1968 and the appearance shortly after of the Review of Radical Political Economics.
In April 1971, Sweezy delivered the prestigious Marshall Lecture at
Cambridge University, entitled “On the Theory of Monopoly Capitalism.”21
With
the advent of economic crisis in 1974–75, URPE brought out its first
“economic crisis reader,” a collection of essays called Radical Perspectives on the Economic Crisis of Monopoly Capitalism,
in which the influence of Baran and Sweezy’s analysis was evident
throughout. Part three of the 1978 edition of another URPE-related
reader, The Capitalist System (first
published in 1972), edited by Richard C. Edwards, Michael Reich, and
Thomas E. Weisskopf, was devoted to “Monopoly Capitalism in the United
States.” It contained selections by Baran and Sweezy, Harry Braverman,
Douglas Dowd, William Domhoff, Stephen Hymer, David Kotz, James
O’Connor, and others.22
Other major works in Marxian political economy in the 1960s and early 1970s inspired in part by Monopoly Capital reinforced
and extended the general critique that it had initiated. In 1969, Harry
Magdoff, who, following Leo Huberman’s death in 1968, had joined Sweezy
as coeditor of Monthly Review, published The Age of Imperialism, providing a detailed economic analysis of U.S. imperialism. James O’Connor’s 1973 The Fiscal Crisis of the State offered
a widely influential radical approach to state spending, building on
the idea of the division of the economy into competitive and monopoly
sectors. Harry Braverman’s 1974 Labor and Monopoly Capital brought Marx’s critique of the labor process into the late twentieth century, integrating it with Baran and Sweezy’s Monopoly Capital—filling the gap left by Baran and Sweezy’s own neglect of the labor process. Samir Amin’s Accumulation on a World Scale, which appeared in an English edition in 1974 (drawing on his doctoral dissertation in the 1950s) linked Monopoly Capital to the global theory of underdevelopment, overlapping in this respect with Baran’s Political Economy of Growth. Stephen Hymer’s definitive work
Δεν υπάρχουν σχόλια:
Δημοσίευση σχολίου
ΚΑΛΗΣΠΕΡΑ ΣΑΣ ΓΙΑ ΣΧΟΛΙΑ, ΑΡΘΡΑ, ΠΑΡΑΤΗΡΗΣΕΙΣ ΚΑΙ ΑΝΑΛΥΣΕΙΣ ΓΙΑ ΤΟ BLOG ΜΑΣ ΜΠΟΡΕΙΤΕ ΝΑ ΜΑΣ ΤΑ ΣΤΕΛΝΕΤΕ ΣΕ ΑΥΤΟ ΤΟ E-MAIL ΔΙΟΤΙ ΤΟ ΕΧΟΥΜΕ ΚΛΕΙΣΤΟ ΓΙΑ ΕΥΝΟΗΤΟΥΣ ΛΟΓΟΥΣ.
Hλεκτρονική διεύθυνση για σχόλια (e-mail) : fioravantes.vas@gmail.com
Σας ευχαριστούμε
Σημείωση: Μόνο ένα μέλος αυτού του ιστολογίου μπορεί να αναρτήσει σχόλιο.